Now Reading
Baumol impact – Wikipedia

Baumol impact – Wikipedia

2023-03-19 11:39:00

Rise of salaries in jobs which have seen little rise of productiveness

In economics, the Baumol impact, often known as Baumol’s price illness, is the rise of wages in jobs which have skilled little or no improve in labor productivity, in response to rising salaries in different jobs which have skilled larger productiveness development. The phenomenon was described by William J. Baumol and William G. Bowen within the Nineteen Sixties[1][2] and is an instance of cross elasticity of demand.

The rise of wages in jobs with out productiveness positive factors derives from the requirement to compete for staff with jobs which have skilled productiveness positive factors and so can naturally pay larger salaries, simply as classical economics predicts. As an example, if the retail sector pays its managers low wages, they might determine to give up and get jobs within the vehicle sector, the place wages are larger due to larger labor productiveness. Thus, retail managers’ salaries improve not attributable to labor productiveness will increase within the retail sector, however attributable to productiveness and corresponding wage will increase in different industries.

Description[edit]

Will increase in labor productiveness are inclined to lead to larger wages.[3][4] Productiveness development shouldn’t be uniform throughout the economic system, nevertheless. Some sectors expertise excessive productiveness development whereas others expertise little or adverse productiveness development.[5] But wages have tended to rise not solely in sectors with excessive productiveness development but in addition in these with little to no productiveness development.

The American economists William J. Baumol and William G. Bowen proposed that wages in sectors with stagnant productiveness rise out of the necessity to compete for staff with sectors that have larger productiveness development, which might afford to lift wages with out elevating costs. With larger labor prices, however little improve in productiveness, sectors with low productiveness development see their prices of manufacturing rise. As summarized by Baumol in a 1967 paper:[6]

If productiveness per man hour rises cumulatively in a single sector relative to its charge of development elsewhere within the economic system, whereas wages rise commensurately in all areas, then relative prices within the nonprogressive sectors should inevitably rise, and these prices will rise cumulatively and with out restrict…Thus, the very progress of the technologically progressive sectors inevitably provides to the prices of the technologically unchanging sectors of the economic system, except by some means the labor markets in these areas could be sealed off and wages held completely fixed, a impossible risk.

Origins[edit]

Performing arts[edit]

The unique examine inspiring the idea of Baumol impact was carried out for the performing arts sector.[1] American economists William J. Baumol and William G. Bowen identified that the identical variety of musicians is required to play a Beethoven string quartet as we speak as was wanted within the nineteenth century—in different phrases, the productiveness of classical music efficiency has not elevated. Nonetheless, the real wages of musicians have elevated considerably for the reason that nineteenth century.

Early references[edit]

The idea was alluded to as early as 1776 by Adam Smith in The Wealth of Nations:[7]

Allow us to suppose, for instance, that within the higher a part of employments the productive powers of labour had been improved to tenfold, or {that a} day’s labour might produce ten instances the amount of labor which it had accomplished initially; however that in a selected employment that they had been improved solely to double, or {that a} day’s labour might produce solely twice the amount of labor which it had accomplished earlier than. In exchanging the produce of a day’s labour within the higher a part of employments for that of a day’s labour on this specific one, ten instances the unique amount of labor in them would buy solely twice the unique amount in it. Any specific amount in it, due to this fact, a pound weight, for instance, would seem like 5 instances dearer than earlier than. In actuality, nevertheless, it will be twice as low cost.

Results[edit]

Because the Baumol impact predicts, between 1998 and 2018 providers grew to become costlier whereas many manufactured items grew to become cheaper

Macroeconomic results[edit]

Value and output[edit]

Firms could reply to will increase in labor prices induced by the Baumol impact in quite a lot of methods, together with:[8]

  • Price and value illness: Costs in stagnant industries are inclined to develop quicker than common
  • Stagnant output: Actual output in low-productivity-growth industries tends to develop extra slowly relative to the general economic system
  • Employment results: Corporations in stagnant industries could cut back employment, lower hours, or improve non-monetary compensation

A 2008 examine by American economist William Nordhaus confirmed as a lot, concluding that “Baumol-type ailments” in technologically stagnant sectors have led to “rising relative costs and declining relative actual outputs”.[8] Within the realm of costs, Nordhaus confirmed that in america from 1948–2001 “productiveness traits are related virtually percentage-point for percentage-point with value decline”. Industries with low productiveness development thus noticed their relative prices improve, main Nordhaus to conclude: “The speculation of a cost-price illness attributable to gradual productiveness development is strongly supported by the historic information. Industries with comparatively decrease productiveness development present a percentage-point
for percentage-point larger development in relative costs.” The same conclusion held for actual output: “The actual output/stagnation speculation is
strongly confirmed. Technologically stagnant industries have proven slower development in actual output than have the technologically dynamic ones. A one percentage-point larger productiveness development was related to a three-quarters percentage-point larger actual output development.”

An essential implication of Baumol impact is that it ought to be anticipated that, in a world with technological progress, the prices of manufactured items will are inclined to fall (as productiveness in manufacturing frequently will increase) whereas the prices of labor-intensive providers like schooling, authorized providers, and well being care (the place productiveness development is persistently gradual) will are inclined to rise (see chart).[a][11]

Affordability[edit]

Whereas Baumol impact means that prices in low-productivity-growth industries will frequently rise, Baumol argues the “stagnant-sector providers won’t ever grow to be unaffordable to society. It is because the economic system’s continuously rising productiveness concurrently will increase the neighborhood’s total purchasing power.”[12] To see this, think about an economic system with an actual nationwide revenue of $100 billion with healthcare spending amounting to $20 billion (20%), leaving $80 billion for different purchases. Say that, over 50 years, attributable to productiveness development actual nationwide revenue doubles to $200 billion (an annual development charge of about 1.4%). To finish up with the identical quantity of revenue left over after healthcare spending as 50 years prior, healthcare spending must rise by 500%, to $120 billion. On this scenario, healthcare would not take up 20% of nationwide revenue however absolutely 60%. If healthcare prices have been to rise to something lower than 60% of nationwide revenue, there can be extra cash left over for different purchases (for example, if healthcare prices have been to rise from 20% of nationwide revenue to 40% of nationwide revenue, there can be $120 billion left over for different purchases—40% greater than 50 years prior). So it may be seen that even when productiveness development have been to result in substantial healthcare price will increase by Baumol’s price illness, the wealth improve introduced on by that productiveness development would nonetheless go away society capable of buy extra items than earlier than.

Authorities spending[edit]

Baumol impact has main implications for government spending. Since most authorities spending goes in direction of providers which are topic to the fee illness—legislation enforcement, schooling, healthcare and so on.—the fee to the federal government of offering these providers will rise as time goes on.[13][14]

Labor pressure distribution[edit]

Employment in america has been rising within the service sector primarily

One implication of the Baumol impact is a shift within the distribution of the labor pressure from high-productivity industries to low-productivity industries.[6] In different phrases, the impact predicts that the share of the workforce employed in low-productivity industries will rise over time.

The rationale for this may be seen by a thought experiment supplied by Baumol in his e book The Price Illness:[15]

Allow us to assume for simplicity that the share of the economic system’s complete output that comes from the progressive sector [industries with high productivity growth], as measured in bodily models relatively than cash, doesn’t change. As a result of the economic system has solely two sectors, progressive and stagnant [industries with low productivity growth], whose manufacturing collectively accounts for all of its output, it follows that the stagnant sector additionally should preserve a relentless share of the overall.
This has important implications for the distribution of the economic system’s labor pressure. By definition, labor productiveness grows considerably quicker within the progressive sector than within the stagnant sector, so to maintain a relentless proportion between the 2 sectors’ output, an increasing number of labor has to maneuver from the progressive sector into the stagnant sector.[b]

As predicted by the Baumol impact, the proportion of america labor pressure employed in stagnant industries has grown considerably for the reason that Nineteen Sixties. Particularly, america has morphed from a producing economic system right into a service economy (see chart).[16] Nonetheless, how a lot of that is as a result of Baumol impact relatively than different causes is disputed.[17][18] In a 2010 examine, the economist Talan B. İşcan devised a mannequin from which he concluded that each Baumol and Engel effects performed important roles within the rising share of employment in providers in america (although he famous that “appreciable gaps between the calibrated mannequin and the precise information stay”).[19] An older 1968 examine by economist Victor Fuchs likewise concluded that the Baumol impact performed a significant function within the shift to providers, though he decided that demand shifts like these proposed in Engel’s legislation performed solely a minor function.[20] The economists Robert Rowthorn and Ramana Ramaswamy additionally concluded that comparatively quicker development of productiveness in manufacturing performed a task within the shift to providers.[21] The economist Tom Elfring, nevertheless, argued in a 1989 paper that the Baumol impact has performed a secondary function to development in demand for providers for the reason that Nineteen Seventies.[22] Different theories for the shift to providers embody demand-side theories (the Baumol impact is broadly a supply-side rationalization) just like the three-sector model devised by Allan Fisher[23] and Colin Clark[24] within the Thirties, which posit that providers fulfill larger wants than items and in order revenue grows a better share of revenue will probably be used for the acquisition of providers;[18] modifications within the inter-industry division of labor, favoring specialised service actions;[18] outsourcing to nations with decrease labor prices;[25] growing participation of girls within the labor pressure;[26] and commerce specialization.[27]

The Baumol impact has additionally been used to explain the reallocation of labor out of agriculture (in 1930, 21.5% of the workforce was employed in agriculture and agriculture made up 7.7% of GDP; by 2000, only one.9% of the workforce was employed in agriculture and agriculture made up solely 0.7% of GDP[28]).[29] In a 2009 examine, the economists Benjamin N. Dennis and Talan B. İşcan concluded that after the Fifties comparatively quicker productiveness development in agriculture was the important thing driver behind the persevering with shift in employment from agriculture to non-farm items (previous to the Fifties, they decided that Engel’s law defined virtually all labor reallocation out of agriculture).[30]

Financial development and mixture productiveness[edit]

In his authentic paper on the fee illness, Baumol argued that in the long term the fee illness implies a discount in mixture productiveness development and correspondingly a discount in economic growth.[6] This follows straightforwardly from the labor distribution effects of the fee illness. As a bigger and bigger share of the workforce strikes from high-productivity-growth industries to low-productivity-growth industries, it’s pure to count on that the general charge of productiveness development will gradual. Since financial development is pushed largely by productiveness development, financial development would additionally gradual.

The economist Nicholas Oulton, nevertheless, argued in a 2001 paper that Baumol impact could counterintuitively lead to an improve in mixture productiveness development.[31] This might happen if many providers produce intermediate inputs for the manufacturing sector, i.e. if a major variety of providers are business services.[c] On this case, although the slow-growth service sector is growing in dimension, as a result of these providers additional increase the productiveness development of the shrinking manufacturing sector total productiveness development may very well improve. Relatedly, the economist Maurizio Pugno described what number of stagnant providers, like schooling and healthcare, contribute to human capital formation, which reinforces development and thus “oppos[es] the adverse Baumol impact on development”.[32]

The economist Hiroaki Sasaki, nevertheless, disputed Oulton’s argument in a 2007 paper.[33] Sasaki constructed an financial mannequin that takes into consideration the usage of providers as intermediate inputs in high-productivity-growth industries and nonetheless concluded {that a} shift in labor pressure distribution from higher-productivity-growth manufacturing to lower-productivity-growth providers decreases the speed of financial development in the long term. Likewise, the economists Jochen Hartwig and Hagen Krämer concluded in a 2019 paper that, whereas Outlon’s idea is “logically constant”, it’s “not consistent with the info”, which exhibits a reducing of mixture productiveness development.[34]

Training[edit]

The Baumol impact has been utilized to the schooling sector,[35][36][37] together with by Baumol himself.[38][39] By most measures, productiveness development within the schooling sector over the past a number of many years has been low and even adverse;[40][41] the typical student-teacher ratio in American universities, for example, was sixteen to 1 in 2011, simply because it was in 1981.[37] But, over this era, tuition prices have risen considerably.[42] It has been proposed that that is not less than partially defined by the Baumol impact: although there was little and even adverse productiveness development within the schooling sector, due to productiveness will increase throughout different sectors of the economic system universities as we speak wouldn’t have the ability to appeal to professors with Nineteen Eighties-level salaries, so they’re pressured to lift wages to take care of their workforce. To afford the elevated labor prices, universities elevate tuition (i.e. they improve costs).[43]

Proof on the function of the Baumol impact in rising schooling prices has been combined. Economists Robert B. Archibald and David H. Feldman, each of the College of William & Mary, argued in a 2006 examine, for example, that the Baumol impact is the dominant driver behind growing larger schooling prices.[44] Different research, nevertheless, have discovered a lesser function for the Baumol impact. In a 2014 examine, the economists Robert E. Martin and Carter Hill devised a mannequin that decided that the Baumol impact defined solely 23%–32% of the rise in larger schooling prices.[45] The economists Gary Rhoades and Joanna Frye went additional in a 2015 examine and argued that the Baumol impact might not clarify rising tuition prices in any respect, as “relative tutorial labor prices have gone down as tuition has gone up”.[46] The fee illness might also have solely restricted results on primary and secondary education: a 2016 examine on per-pupil public schooling spending by Manabu Nostril, an economist on the International Monetary Fund, discovered that “the contribution of Baumol’s impact was a lot smaller than implied by idea”; Nostril argued that it was as an alternative rising wage premiums paid for academics in extra of market wages that have been the dominant motive for growing prices, notably in developing countries.[47]

Different explanations for rising larger schooling prices embody Bowen’s revenue theory of cost,[45][48] diminished public subsidies for schooling,[49][50] administrative bloat,[49][51] the commercialization of upper schooling,[52] elevated demand for larger schooling,[53] the straightforward availability of federal pupil loans,[54][55] issue evaluating costs of various universities,[56] technological change,[36] and lack of a central mechanism to manage value will increase.[50]

Healthcare[edit]

The Baumol impact has been utilized to the rising price of healthcare,[39] because the healthcare {industry} has lengthy had low productiveness development.[57][58] Empirical research have largely confirmed the massive function of the Baumol impact within the rising price of healthcare in america,[59][60][61][62][63] though there may be some disagreement.[64] Likewise, a 2021 examine decided that “Baumol’s price illness ha[s] a major constructive influence on well being expenditure development” in China.[65] Nonetheless, a paper by economists Bradley Rossen and Akhter Faroque on healthcare prices in Canada discovered that “the fee illness…is a comparatively minor contributor [in the growth of health-care spending in Canada], whereas technical progress in well being care and development in per capita incomes are by far the largest contributors”.[66]

Regardless of substantial technological innovation and capital funding, the healthcare {industry} has struggled to considerably improve productiveness. As summarized by the economists Alberto Marino, David Morgan, Luca Lorenzoni, and Chris James:[67]

“Technological developments, capital investments and economies of scale don’t make for a cumulative rise in output that’s on par with progressive sectors of the economic system…[A]utomation and higher know-how typically don’t permit for giant productiveness will increase. A well being skilled is troublesome to substitute, particularly through the use of new applied sciences, which can truly additionally deliver a rise in quantity (e.g. quicker diagnostic checks). Will increase in quantity doubtless caused by new know-how may also drive up expenditure, since new well being professionals should be employed to deal with everybody. Furthermore, new applied sciences require extra specialised coaching for say [sic] medical doctors, driving wages up additional since extra years of expertise are required.”

Service {industry}[edit]

Baumol’s price illness is commonly used to explain penalties of the shortage of development in productiveness within the quaternary sector of the economy and public services, comparable to public hospitals and state faculties.[35] Labor-intensive sectors that rely closely on non-routine human interplay or actions, comparable to health care, education, or the performing arts, have had much less development in productiveness over time. As with the string quartet instance, it takes nurses the identical period of time to vary a bandage or faculty professors the identical period of time to mark an essay as we speak because it did in 1966, as these varieties of actions depend on the actions of the human physique, which can’t but be engineered to carry out extra rapidly, precisely, or effectively in the identical approach {that a} machine, comparable to a pc, have.[68] In distinction, goods-producing industries, such because the automobile manufacturing sector and different actions that contain routine duties, staff are frequently turning into extra productive by technological improvements to their instruments and gear.

The reported productiveness positive factors of the service {industry} within the late Nineteen Nineties are largely attributable to complete issue productiveness.[69] Suppliers decreased the price of ancillary labor by outsourcing or know-how. Examples embody offshoring information entry and bookkeeping for well being care suppliers and changing manually-marked essays in academic evaluation with multiple choice checks that may be automatically marked.

Technical description[edit]

Within the 1967 paper Macroeconomics of Unbalanced Development: The Anatomy of City Disaster, Baumol launched a easy two-sector mannequin to reveal the fee illness.[6] To take action, he imagined an economic system consisting of solely two sectors: sector one, which has fixed productiveness (that’s, the variety of items staff can produce per man hour doesn’t change as time goes on), and sector two, which sees productiveness develop at a relentless compounded charge (that’s, the variety of items staff can produce per man hour grows at a charge , the place is time). To simplify, he assumed that the amount of products produced by these two sectors (the “output” of every of the 2 sectors) is immediately proportional to the amount of labor employed (that’s, doubling the variety of staff doubles the output, tripling the variety of staff triples the output, and so forth) and that output relies upon solely upon labor productiveness and the amount of labor. Since there is no such thing as a improve in labor productiveness in sector one, the output of sector one at time (denoted ) is:

See Also

the place is the amount of labor employed in sector one and is a continuing that may be regarded as the quantity of output every employee can produce at time . This equation merely says that the quantity of output sector one produces equals the variety of staff in sector one multiplied by the variety of items every employee can produce. Since productiveness doesn’t improve, the variety of items every employee produces stays and output stays fixed by time.

Because the labor productiveness of sector two will increase at a relentless compounded charge , the output of sector two at time (denoted ) is:

the place is the amount of labor employed in sector two and is a continuing that may be regarded as the quantity of output every employee can produce at time . Since productiveness grows at a relentless compounded charge , the variety of items every employee produces at time equals , and the output of sector two grows at a charge proportional to productiveness development.

To extra clearly reveal how wages and prices change by time, wages in each sectors are initially set on the similar worth . It’s then assumed that wages rise in direct proportion to productiveness (i.e., a doubling of productiveness ends in a doubling of wages, a tripling of productiveness ends in a tripling of wages, and so forth). Because of this the wages of the 2 sectors at time decided solely by productiveness are:

(since productiveness stays unchanged), and
(since productiveness will increase at a charge )

These values, nevertheless, assume that staff don’t transfer between the 2 sectors. If staff are equally able to working in both sector, and so they select which sector to work in primarily based upon which provides a better wage, then they’ll at all times select to work within the sector that provides the upper wage. Because of this if sector one have been to maintain wages mounted at , then as wages in sector two develop with productiveness staff in sector one would give up and search jobs in sector two. Corporations in sector one are thus pressured to lift wages to draw staff. Extra exactly, on this mannequin the one approach corporations in both sector can appeal to staff is to supply the identical wage as corporations within the different sector—if one sector have been to supply decrease wages, then all staff would work within the different sector.

So to take care of their workforces, wages within the two sectors should equal one another: . And since it’s sector two that sees its wage naturally rise with productiveness, whereas sector one’s doesn’t naturally rise, it should be the case that:

.

This typifies the labor side of the Baumol impact: as productiveness development in a single sector of the economic system drives up that sector’s wages, corporations in sectors with out productiveness development should additionally elevate wages to compete for staff.[d]

From this easy mannequin, the results on the prices per unit output within the two sectors could be derived. Because the solely factor of production inside this mannequin is labor, every sector’s complete price is the wage paid to staff multiplied by the overall variety of staff. The fee per unit output is the overall price divided by the quantity of output, so with representing the unit price of products in sector one at time and representing the unit price of products in sector two at time :

Plugging within the values for and from above:

It may be seen that within the sector with rising labor productiveness (sector two), the fee per unit output is fixed since each wages and output rise on the similar charge. Nonetheless, within the sector with stagnant labor productiveness (sector one), the fee per unit output rises exponentially since wages rise exponentially quicker than output.

This demonstrates the fee side of the Baumol impact (the “price illness”). Whereas prices in sectors with productiveness development—and therefore wage development—needn’t improve, in sectors with little to no productiveness development (who nonetheless should elevate wages to compete for staff) prices essentially rise. Moreover, if the productiveness development differential persists (that’s, the low-productivity-growth sectors proceed to see low productiveness development into the longer term whereas high-productivity-growth sectors proceed to see excessive productiveness development), then prices in low-productivity-growth sectors will rise cumulatively and with out restrict.

Baumol’s mannequin will also be used to reveal the impact on the distribution of labor. Assume that, regardless of the change within the relative prices and costs of the 2 industries, the magnitude of the relative outputs of the 2 sectors are maintained. A scenario just like this might happen, for example, “with assistance from authorities subsidy, or if demand for the product in query have been sufficiently value inelastic or revenue elastic”. The output ratio and its relation to the labor ratio, ignoring constants and , is then given by:

Letting (i.e. is the overall labor provide), it follows that:

or

It may be seen that as approaches infinity, the amount of labor within the non-progressive sector approaches the overall labor provide whereas the amount of labor within the progressive sector approaches zero. Therefore, “if the ratio of the outputs of the 2 sectors is held fixed, an increasing number of of the overall labor pressure should be transferred to the non-progressive sector and the quantity of labor within the different sector will are inclined to method zero”.

See additionally[edit]

  1. ^ Observe that low productiveness development doesn’t afflict all services. Telecommunications, for instance, has seen substantial productiveness development.[9] Service industries are merely extra doubtless than manufactured items industries to be resistant to productiveness development, for the explanations that they’re typically much less capable of be standardized and that the standard of providers usually tend to be carefully linked to the quantity of labor supplied.[10]
  2. ^ A technical description of this impact could be present in Technical description
  3. ^ Within the two-sector mannequin Baumol devised in his authentic paper (see Technical description), providers are produced just for final consumption.
  4. ^ Observe that that is an assumption of the mannequin. As Baumol states within the authentic paper, “We suppose wages are equal within the two sectors and are mounted at {dollars} per unit of labor, the place itself grows in accord with the productiveness of sector 2, our ‘progressive’ sector.” The previous two paragraphs merely reveal the logic of that assumption.

References[edit]

  1. ^ a b Baumol, W. J.; Bowen, W. G. (March 1965). “On the Performing Arts: The Anatomy of Their Economic Problems” (PDF). The American Economic Review. 55 (1/2): 495–502. JSTOR 1816292.
  2. ^ Baumol, William J.; Bowen, William G. (1966). Performing Arts, The Economic Dilemma: A Study of Problems Common to Theater, Opera, Music, and Dance. Cambridge, Mass.: M.I.T. Press. ISBN 0262520117.
  3. ^ Anderson, Richard G. (2007). “How Well Do Wages Follow Productivity Growth?” (PDF). Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Archived (PDF) from the unique on December 3, 2021. Retrieved March 1, 2022.
  4. ^ Feldstein, Martin (July 2008). “Did wages reflect growth in productivity?” (PDF). Journal of Policy Modeling. 30 (4): 591–594. doi:10.1016/j.jpolmod.2008.04.003.
  5. ^ Baily, Martin Neil; Bosworth, Barry; Doshi, Siddhi (January 2020). “Productivity comparisons: Lessons from Japan, the United States, and Germany” (PDF). Brookings Institution. p. 14. Archived (PDF) from the unique on December 18, 2021. Retrieved March 1, 2022.
  6. ^ a b c d Baumol, William J. (June 1967). “Macroeconomics of Unbalanced Growth: The Anatomy of Urban Crisis” (PDF). The American Economic Review. 57 (3): 415–426. JSTOR 1812111. Archived (PDF) from the unique on February 26, 2022.
  7. ^ “An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, by Adam Smith”. www.gutenberg.org. Retrieved August 29, 2020.
  8. ^ a b Norhaus, William D. (February 2008). “Baumol’s Diseases: A Macroeconomic Perspective” (PDF). The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics. 8 (1). doi:10.2202/1935-1690.1382. S2CID 153319511 – through NBER.
  9. ^ Modica, Nathan F.; Chansky, Brian (Could 2019). “Productivity trends in the wired and wireless telecommunications industries” (PDF). Bureau of Labor Statistics. Archived (PDF) from the unique on January 14, 2022. Retrieved March 24, 2022.
  10. ^ Baumol, William J. (2012). The Cost Disease: Why Computers Get Cheaper and Health Care Doesn’t. New Haven: Yale University Press. pp. 22–24. ISBN 978-0300198157.
  11. ^ Lee, Timothy B. (Could 4, 2017). “William Baumol, whose famous economic theory explains the modern world, has died”. Vox. Archived from the unique on January 31, 2022. Retrieved March 1, 2022.
  12. ^ Baumol, William J. (2012). The Cost Disease: Why Computers Get Cheaper and Health Care Doesn’t. New Haven: Yale University Press. pp. xx. ISBN 978-0300198157.
  13. ^ Baumol, William J. (2012). The Cost Disease: Why Computers Get Cheaper and Health Care Doesn’t. New Haven: Yale University Press. p. 27. ISBN 978-0300198157.
  14. ^ Baumol, William J. (September 1993). “Health care, education and the cost disease: A looming crisis for public choice”. Public Choice. 77 (1): 17–28. doi:10.1007/978-94-017-3402-8_3. ISBN 978-94-017-3404-2. S2CID 154871885 – through Springer Publishing.
  15. ^ Baumol, William J. (2012). The Cost Disease: Why Computers Get Cheaper and Health Care Doesn’t. New Haven: Yale University Press. p. 80. ISBN 978-0300198157.
  16. ^ Brief, Doug (September 5, 2011). “Charting The Incredible Shift From Manufacturing To Services In America”. Insider Inc. Archived from the unique on April 21, 2021. Retrieved March 26, 2022.
  17. ^ Urquhart, Michael (April 1984). “The employment shift to services: where did it come from?” (PDF). Monthly Labor Review. 107 (4): 15–22. Archived from the original (PDF) on January 30, 2022 – through Bureau of Labor Statistics. Advised explanations for the quicker development of providers employment embody modifications within the demand for items and providers on account of rising incomes and relative value actions, slower productiveness development in providers, the growing participation of girls within the labor pressure since World Conflict II, and the rising significance of the general public and nonprofit sector usually. However no consensus exists on the relative significance of the above components in growing an satisfactory rationalization of the sectoral shifts in employment.
  18. ^ a b c Schettkat, Ronald; Yocarini, Lara (January 13, 2004). “The Shift to Services: A Review of the Literature”. Social Science Research Network. doi:10.2139/ssrn.487282. S2CID 154141056. SSRN 487282. Archived (PDF) from the unique on April 12, 2021. Retrieved March 26, 2022.
  19. ^ İşcan, Talan B. (January 2010). “How Much Can Engel’s Law and Baumol’s Disease Explain the Rise of Service Employment in the United States?”. The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics. 10 (1): 1–43. doi:10.2202/1935-1690.2001. S2CID 154824000 – through De Gruyter.
  20. ^ Fuchs, Victor (1968). The Service Economic system. National Bureau of Economic Research. ISBN 978-0870144769.
  21. ^ Rowthorn, Robert; Ramaswamy, Ramana (1999). “Growth, Trade, and Deindustrialization” (PDF). IMF Workers Papers. 46 (1): 18–41. Archived (PDF) from the unique on January 26, 2022 – through International Monetary Fund.
  22. ^ Elfring, Tom (1989). “The Main Features and Underlying Causes of the Shift to Services”. The Service Industries Journal. 9 (3): 337–356. doi:10.1080/02642068900000040 – through Taylor & Francis.
  23. ^ Fisher, Allan G.B. (1935). The Conflict of Progress and Safety. Macmillan Publishers. ISBN 9780678001585.
  24. ^ Clark, Colin (1940). The Situations of Financial Progress. Macmillan Publishers. ISBN 9780598475732.
  25. ^ Scharpf, F. W. (1990). “Buildings of Postindustrial Society or Does Mass Unemployment Disappear within the Service and Data Economic system”. In Appelbaum, E. (ed.). Labor Market Changes to Structural Change and Technological Progress. New York: Praeger Publishers. pp. 17–36. ISBN 978-0-275-93376-0.
  26. ^ Urquhart, Michael (April 1984). “The employment shift to services: where did it come from?” (PDF). Monthly Labor Review. 107 (4): 15–22. Archived from the original (PDF) on January 30, 2022.
  27. ^ Rowthorn, R. E.; Wells, J.R. (1987). De-Industrialization and Overseas Commerce. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0521269476.
  28. ^ Dimitri, Carolyn; Effland, Anne; Conklin, Neilson (June 2005). “The 20th Century Transformation of U.S. Agriculture and Farm Policy” (PDF). United States Department of Agriculture. Archived (PDF) from the unique on March 24, 2022. Retrieved March 26, 2022.
  29. ^ Baumol, William J. (2012). The Cost Disease: Why Computers Get Cheaper and Health Care Doesn’t. New Haven: Yale University Press. pp. 117–119. ISBN 978-0300198157.
  30. ^ Dennis, Benjamin N.; İşcan, Talan B. (April 2009). “Engel versus Baumol: Accounting for structural change using two centuries of U.S. data”. Explorations in Economic History. 46 (2): 186–202. doi:10.1016/j.eeh.2008.11.003 – through ScienceDirect.
  31. ^ Oulton, Nicholas (October 2001). “Must the growth rate decline? Baumol’s unbalanced growth revisited”. Oxford Financial Papers. 53 (4): 605–627. doi:10.1093/oep/53.4.605 – through Oxford University Press.
  32. ^ Pugno, Maurizio (January 2006). “The service paradox and endogenous economic growth”. Structural Change and Financial Dynamics. 17 (1): 99–115. doi:10.1016/j.strueco.2005.02.003 – through ScienceDirect.
  33. ^ Sasaki, Hiroaki (December 2007). “The rise of service employment and its impact on aggregate productivity growth”. Structural Change and Financial Dynamics. 18 (4): 438–459. doi:10.1016/j.strueco.2007.06.003 – through ScienceDirect.
  34. ^ Hartwig, Jochen; Krämer, Hagen (December 2019). “The ‘Growth Disease’ at 50 – Baumol after Oulton”. Structural Change and Financial Dynamics. 51: 463–471. doi:10.1016/j.strueco.2019.02.006. hdl:10419/170670. S2CID 115407478 – through ScienceDirect.
  35. ^ a b Helland, Eric; Alexander Tabarrok (2019). “Why Are the Prices So Damn High? Health, Education, and the Baumol Effect” (PDF). Mercatus Center.
  36. ^ a b Archibald, Robert B.; Feldman, David H. (2014). Why Does Faculty Price So A lot?. Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-0190214104.
  37. ^ a b Surowiecki, James (November 13, 2011). “Debt by Degrees”. The New Yorker.
  38. ^ Baumol, William J. (June 1967). “Macroeconomics of Unbalanced Growth: The Anatomy of Urban Crisis” (PDF). The American Economic Review. 57 (3): 415–426. JSTOR 1812111. Archived (PDF) from the unique on February 26, 2022. The comparatively fixed productiveness of school instructing…means that, as productiveness within the the rest of the economic system continues to extend, prices of operating the academic organizations will mount correspondingly, in order that regardless of the magnitude of the funds they want as we speak, we could be moderately sure that they’ll require extra tomorrow, and much more on the day after that.
  39. ^ a b Baumol, William J. (2012). The Cost Disease: Why Computers Get Cheaper and Health Care Doesn’t. New Haven: Yale University Press. pp. 3–32. ISBN 978-0300198157.
  40. ^ “Labor Productivity and Costs: Elementary and Secondary Schools”. Bureau of Labor Statistics. February 23, 2018. Archived from the unique on January 4, 2022. Retrieved February 27, 2022.
  41. ^ Garrett, Thomas A; Poole, William (January 1, 2006). “Stop Paying More for Less: Ways to Boost Productivity in Higher Education”. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Archived from the unique on January 11, 2022. Retrieved February 27, 2022.
  42. ^ Carnevale, Anthony P.; Gulish, Artem; Campbell, Kathryn Peltier (2021). “If Not Now, When? The Urgent Need for an All-One-System Approach to Youth Policy” (PDF). McCourt School of Public Policy: Middle on Training and the Workforce. Georgetown University. p. 13. Archived (PDF) from the unique on October 20, 2021. Retrieved February 27, 2022.
  43. ^ Bundick, Brent; Pollard, Emily (2019). “The Rise and Fall of College Tuition Inflation” (PDF). Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City. Archived (PDF) from the unique on December 17, 2021. Retrieved February 27, 2022.
  44. ^ Archibald, Robert B.; Feldman, David H. (October 21, 2016). “Explaining Increases in Higher Education Costs” (PDF). The Journal of Higher Education. 79 (3): 268–295. doi:10.1080/00221546.2008.11772099. S2CID 158250944.
  45. ^ a b Martin, Robert E.; Hill, R. Carter (March 2014). “Baumol and Bowen Cost Effects in Research Universities”. doi:10.2139/ssrn.2153122. S2CID 153016802. SSRN 2153122 – through SSRN. CS1 maint: url-status (link)
  46. ^ Rhoades, Gary; Frye, Joanna (April 2015). “College tuition increases and faculty labor costs: A counterintuitive disconnect” (PDF). University of Arizona. Archived (PDF) from the unique on October 2, 2021. Retrieved February 27, 2021.
  47. ^ Nostril, Manabu (July 9, 2016). “Estimation of drivers of public education expenditure: Baumol’s effect revisited”. Worldwide Tax and Public Finance. 24 (3): 512–535. doi:10.1007/s10797-016-9410-7. S2CID 155747172 – through SpringerLink.
  48. ^ Matthews, Dylan (September 2, 2013). “The Tuition is Too Damn High, Part VI — Why there’s no reason for big universities to rein in spending”. The Washington Post. Archived from the unique on November 13, 2020. Retrieved March 25, 2022.
  49. ^ a b Martin, Robert (2002). “Why Tuition Costs Are Rising So Quickly”. Challenge. 45 (2): 88–108. doi:10.1080/05775132.2002.11034164 – through Taylor & Francis.
  50. ^ a b Ripley, Amanda (September 11, 2018). “Why Is College in America So Expensive?”. The Atlantic. Archived from the unique on March 24, 2022. Retrieved March 25, 2022.
  51. ^ Johnson, J. David (2020). “Administrative Bloat in Higher Education” (PDF). Cambridge Scholars Publishing. Archived (PDF) from the unique on October 13, 2021. Retrieved March 25, 2022.
  52. ^ Renehan, Stewart (August 2015). “Rising Tuition in Higher Education: Should we be Concerned?”. Visions for the Liberal Arts. 1 (1) – through CORE.
  53. ^ Hoffower, Hillary (June 26, 2019). “College is more expensive than it’s ever been, and the 5 reasons why suggest it’s only going to get worse”. Insider Inc. Archived from the unique on March 23, 2022. Retrieved March 25, 2022.
  54. ^ Bennet, William J. (February 18, 1987). “Our Greedy Colleges”. The New York Times. Archived from the unique on January 27, 2022. Retrieved March 25, 2022.
  55. ^ Robinson, Jenna A. (December 2017). “The Bennett Hypothesis Turns 30” (PDF). James G. Martin Center for Academic Renewal. Archived (PDF) from the unique on January 28, 2021. Retrieved March 25, 2022.
  56. ^ Akers, Beth (August 27, 2020). “A New Approach for Curbing College Tuition Inflation”. Manhattan Institute for Policy Research. Archived from the unique on November 29, 2021. Retrieved March 25, 2022.
  57. ^ Sheiner, Louise; Malinovskaya, Anna (Could 2016). “Measuring Productivity in Healthcare: An Analysis of the Literature” (PDF). Brookings Institution. Archived (PDF) from the unique on March 24, 2022. Retrieved March 26, 2022.
  58. ^ “Labor Productivity and Costs: Private Community Hospitals”. Bureau of Labor Statistics. June 11, 2021. Archived from the unique on January 4, 2022. Retrieved March 26, 2022.
  59. ^ Colombier, Carsten (November 2017). “Drivers of Health-Care Expenditure: What Role Does Baumol’s Cost Disease Play?”. Social Science Quarterly. 98 (5): 1603–1621. doi:10.1111/ssqu.12384 – through Wiley.
  60. ^ Hartwig, Jochen (Could 2008). “What drives health care expenditure?—Baumol’s model of ‘unbalanced growth’ revisited”. Journal of Health Economics. 27 (3): 603–623. doi:10.2139/ssrn.910879. hdl:10419/50843. PMID 18164773. S2CID 219356527. SSRN 910879 – through Social Science Research Network.
  61. ^ Hartwig, Jochen (April 2009). “Can Baumol’s model of unbalanced growth contribute to explaining the secular rise in health care expenditure? An alternative test”. Applied Economics. 43 (2): 173–184. doi:10.1080/00036840802400470. hdl:10419/50451. S2CID 154307473 – through Taylor & Francis.
  62. ^ Bates, Laurie J.; Santerre, Rexford E. (March 2013). “Does the U.S. health care sector suffer from Baumol’s cost disease? Evidence from the 50 states”. Journal of Health Economics. 32 (2): 386–391. doi:10.1016/j.jhealeco.2012.12.003. PMID 23348051 – through ScienceDirect.
  63. ^ Pomp, Marc; Vujić, Sunčica (December 2008). “Rising health spending, new medical technology and the Baumol effect” (PDF). Bureau for Economic Policy Analysis. Archived (PDF) from the unique on January 22, 2022. Retrieved March 26, 2022.
  64. ^ Atanda, Akinwande; Menclova, Andrea Kutinova; Reed, W. Robert (February 2018). “Is health care infected by Baumol’s cost disease? Test of a new model”. Well being Economics. 27 (5): 832–849. doi:10.1002/hec.3641. PMID 29423941. S2CID 46855963 – through Wiley.
  65. ^ Wang, Linan; Chen, Yuqian (2021). “Determinants of China’s health expenditure growth: based on Baumol’s cost disease theory”. Worldwide Journal for Fairness in Well being. 20 (1): 213. doi:10.1186/s12939-021-01550-y. PMC 8474747. PMID 34565389. S2CID 233774285.
  66. ^ Rossen, Bradley; Faroque, Akhter (Spring 2016). “Diagnosing the Causes of Rising Health-Care Expenditure in Canada: Does Baumol’s Cost Disease Loom Large?”. American Journal of Well being Economics. 2 (2): 184–212. doi:10.1162/AJHE_a_00041. S2CID 57569390 – through University of Chicago.
  67. ^ Marino, Alberto; Morgan, David; Lorenzoni, Luca; James, Chris (June 2017). “Future trends in health care expenditure: A modelling framework for cross-country forecasts”. OECD Well being Working Papers. 95. doi:10.1787/247995bb-en – through OECD.
  68. ^ Surowiecki, James (July 7, 2003). “What Ails Us”. The New Yorker. Archived from the original on Could 9, 2021.
  69. ^ Bosworth, Barry P; Jack E Triplett (September 1, 2003). “Productivity Measurement Issues in Services Industries: “Baumol’s Disease” Has been Cured”. Brookings Institution.

Exterior hyperlinks[edit]


Source Link

What's Your Reaction?
Excited
0
Happy
0
In Love
0
Not Sure
0
Silly
0
View Comments (0)

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published.

2022 Blinking Robots.
WordPress by Doejo

Scroll To Top